Blaming
The Victim: - Paul
McKeever
The "break-up
of Canada"? It's a possibility that the federal government frequently
blames on secessionist leanings in Quebec and the West. But are
these movements the cause of what ails Canada, or are
they symptoms? For an answer, one need only look at the
genesis of secessionist sentiments.
Arguably,
the genesis of Quebec and Western secessionist sentiments lies
in the history of the so-called "Rule of Law". In theory, our
constitution is our supreme ruler, and all --- including politicians
and monarchs --- are bound to obey it.
In
1867, the British North America Act (part of our constitution)
ended a 27 year attempt to wash-out French culture by uniting
Upper and Lower Canada. The BNA Act (now properly called the Constitution
Act, 1867) returned a jurisdiction and undiluted vote to
Lower Canada (therein re-named Quebec). It created the federal
Parliament, which was given some of the legislative power previously
held by the individual colonies. But, to the exclusion of the
federal Parliament, it reserved to the provinces the power to
make certain types of laws. Even today, our federal Parliament
and provincial Legislatures have only the law-making powers given
to them by the BNA Act.
The
BNA Act gives only to the provincial Legislatures the power to
make laws relating to education and health care. And, until World
War I, it was not contested that only the provincial Legislatures
have the power to make laws that impose a direct tax (e.g., income
tax, GST). But, in 1917, the federal government made a law that
imposed a "temporary" income tax, purportedly to raise revenues
for the war.
In
response, a Quebec civil servant named Caron argued that the
federal Parliament lacked the power to make such a law. The result,
in 1924, was a decision by our then highest court (see www.ownlife.com/tax/caron1.htm)
that the federal government can impose a direct tax if it raises "a
revenue for federal purposes" (like the military) , but not if
it raises "a revenue for provincial purposes" (like education
or health care). At the time, federal revenues were not spent
on provincial purposes, so the income tax was held to be enforceable.
However, subsequent federal spending on provincial purposes has
put the enforceability of some federal taxes into doubt (see,
for example, www.ownlife.com/tax/dmcsherm.htm or,
in Consent #24, "Is the
Federal Income Tax Act Unconstitutional?")
In
1929, the stock market crashed. A great economic depression followed.
As the U.S. Federal Reserve's Alan Greenspan explained
in Ayn Rand's book Capitalism: The Unknown Ideal,
the crash appears to have been caused primarily by inflation
of the supply of government-issued force-backed (fiat) paper
money. But, at the time, Keynesians, socialists and other authoritarians
--- arguably for political reasons --- blamed the crash upon
the free market. Promising to protect the poor with taxes on
the "rich" and government spending programs, authoritarians in
the industrialized world were voted into power: a welfare state
was an easy sell during the depression. Authoritarian governments
(in Canada, Liberals and Progressive Conservatives) essentially
took away from individuals the freedom to make economic decisions
for themselves, and transferred their power to a single, centralized
government.
In
Canada, the division of taxing powers between the federal and
provincial legislatures was seen as an obstacle to effectively
centralized control of the economy. Moreover, with only the power
to impose an indirect tax (e.g. a retail sales tax), it would
have been difficult for a federal government to impose higher
rates of taxation on those with higher incomes (as was eventually
done). So, promising to pay off the debts of the provinces and
to pay them a "rent", the federal government persuaded most of
the provinces to relinquish their jurisdiction over direct taxation.
The
way was thereby paved for effectively centralized, authoritarian
control of the Canadian economy.
The
constitution posed another pesky obstacle to centralized economic
control. Specifically, until the rise of the authoritarians in
the 1930s, governments had interpreted the constitution as allowing
a government to spend only upon those things respecting which
it could pass laws (e.g., the federal government could spend
on criminal law, but not on exclusively provincial matters such
as education; the provinces could spend on health care, but not
on the military). Thus, the federal government literally invented
the idea that its spending powers were unlimited. Making this
bald assertion (an unlimited spending power is set out nowhere
in the constitution), the federal government gradually circumvented
the division of legislative powers set out in the Act by making
so-called "conditional grants" of money to the provinces: provinces
who dared not to make certain laws according to federal specifications
would be denied their share of the grant.
The
federal centralization of economic decision-making powers posed
an obvious threat to French culture in Quebec. The BNA Act had
been designed, in part, to protect French culture by limiting
federal power.
Thus,
almost from the outset of the authoritarians' attempts to circumvent
constitutional limits on federal power via taxing and spending,
Quebec protested loudly. It refused after the second World War
to enter into tax rental and tax collection agreements. In the
1950s, Premier Duplessis struck a Royal Commission (the Tremblay
Commission), the primary purpose of which was to demonstrate
that only the provinces had the constitutionally-conferred power
to make a law which imposes a direct tax. And, in 1957 (before
he became a federal politician), Pierre Trudeau, addressing the
issue of federal spending on universities, demonstrated the supposedly
unlimited spending power to be a myth (see his 1968 Federalism
and the French Canadians, p. 79: "Federal Grants to Universities").
But
federal authoritarians continued their attack and dug deep trenches.
In The Allocation of Taxing Power Under the Canadian Constitution (Canadian
Tax Foundation, Canadian Tax Paper No. 65), then law professor
Gerard La Forest recognized the limits placed on the federal
Parliament's taxation powers but suggested that "the [words]
of the [judges in the Caron decision] should probably be ignored.
They were made when the device of transfer payments might still
have been considered doubtful." He was later appointed by the
federal Prime Minister to the Supreme Court of Canada, where
he decided that, as a matter of policy, taxpayers should not
be refunded money which is taken from them by means of an unconstitutional
tax.
On
the spending side, federally appointed judges have stated that
conditional grants to provinces are not under-handed attempts
to circumvent the jurisdictional limits set out in the constitution.
And, despite his earlier writings, Pierre Trudeau did not hesitate
to engage in such spending as federal Liberal Prime Minister.
The centralization of economic decision-making power was, and
remains, extended and secured.
Over
the decades since the rise of federal authoritarianism, Quebec's
struggle to have the federal government respect the limits of
its own power bore little fruit. Many Quebecers, having lost
much provincial power, fearing the loss of their heritage and
culture, and losing faith in the idea that the federal government
would once again respect the terms of union set out in the BNA
Act, turned their gaze to the only alternative: taking back the
legislative powers it had given up to the federal Parliament
in 1867 (i.e., secession). If the federal government was unwilling
to respect the stated terms of the provincial partnership, the
partnership would have to end.
The
secession of Quebec could be very costly for the rest of Canada.
And so it became the practice of the federal government to bribe
Quebecers not to secede by giving Quebec relatively high shares
of the federal spoils: by making the federal government seem
indispensable to Quebecers despite federal violations of the
terms of union. But that could not be done without providing
the rest of Canada with a reason. So, rather than accepting any
blame for separatist sentiment in Quebec, rather than telling
the rest of Canada that federal hand-outs to Quebec were to quell
the separatist feelings caused by federal circumvention of the
constitution, Quebec was blamed. All of Quebec separatism was
characterized as a movement born not of reaction to federal usurpation
of provincial power, but merely of French bigotry and hatred
toward English-speaking Canada.
And
the rest of Canada was duped.
Today,
most Canadians (including lawyers) know little or nothing about
federal circumvention of the constitutional limits of federal
power, but many people think of Quebec as a province of spoiled
extortionists. A victim of federal authoritarianism has been
successfully blamed, and Canada's biggest champion for the rule
of law slandered.
And,
of course, federal strong-arm tactics in the West have added
steam to Western secessionist sentiments. For example, any provincial
talk of providing Albertans with quicker, better medical care
through free market medical clinics is met with federal threats
to Alberta's share of (arguably illegal) federal health funds.
But Alberta, by taking such steps as decoupling its income tax
regime from that of the federal government, is working steadily
toward a more autonomous state of affairs.
Whereas
the secession of some provinces from federal jurisdiction (usually
called the "Break up of Canada") is a clear and undesirable possibility,
Canadians must not allow the federal government to make scapegoats
out of the provinces. Clearly, secessionist sentiments in Quebec
and the West are the result of federal Liberal and PC centralization
of the economy (and the Canadian Alliance is following suit with
calls for more federal funding for health care).
Money,
and the power to interfere with the free market, is the lifeblood
of authoritarianism. In Canada, the federal government must continue
to circumvent the constitution and usurp provincial power if
it is to maintain its power to interfere with the free market.
Such circumvention is --- to any intellectually honest person
--- anti-democratic.
Democracy
is the process by which the governed determine the laws of the
land: law is the only direct product of democracy. So, when a
government refuses to let its actions be governed by law ---
when, for example, it skirts constitutional limits on its legislative
power and exercises unlimited force by virtue of an unlimited
spending power --- the country ceases to be governed in a democratic
way. Democracy is replaced with tyranny. That we vote our tyrants
into power does not mean that we live in a democracy.
What
does this mean for the voter? It means that we must recognize
that the survival of Canada depends upon democracy (by which,
I am not implying majority rule). It means that, to regain and
preserve democracy, we must elect only those persons and parties
that are committed to respecting the constitutional limits of
federal power. And, because an authoritarian federal government
cannot meet its objective in Canada if the constitution is respected,
democracy demands that we vote out of power our authoritarian
politicians in the federal Parliament. Democracy and the abatement
of secessionist sentiments require that we vote in favour of
federal politicians and parties that will discontinue the practice
of using direct taxation and unlimited spending to usurp provincial
economic decision-making power.
The
break-up of Canada? If we continue to vote for authoritarian
party members (especially in Ontario), we will have nobody to
blame but ourselves. |